App Store
Image via Wikipedia

Recently, I received the following email from a friend:

Dear iphone/ipod wielding friends,

I need a 99 cent favor. I just published my new app and I need a little help getting noticed. Unfortunately, the app store has a popularity driven system. To do well, you need to get into the top 100 list. Would you guys buy the app? I will generously reimburse you! If you can do it today, that would be great! You can use this link …

While I removed some information from the email so as to protect the identity of the sender, I have to tell you that my friend is a smart man and well-versed in online economic systems.  Perhaps this is why he sent out the email.

The gaming of rating services is not new.  An analysis of Amazon.com revealed that hundreds of product reviews are merely copied in part (or in whole) from other product reviews.  Sellers and buyers using eBay’s reputation system are constantly under scrutiny against manipulating their own ratings.

Nor are academics immune from ratings manipulation.  University administrators often engage in behavior designed to increase their institution’s ranking in US News & World Report, and professors are known boost their own ratings on the online website, RateMyProfessors.com, by posing as students.

More recently, Elsevier was admonished for offering $25 Amazon gift cards to academic contributors, their colleagues, and their students willing to give  a 5-star rating to a newly published textbook.

My point here is that recommender systems are game-able, especially when contributors are anonymous or when the digital marketplace allows the easy creation of pseudonyms and sock puppets.

The effects of early promotion  are clear to those in business as well as academia:  downloads encourage further downloads, readership begets more readership, and citations beget more citations.  In social environments where users see traces of peer behavior, small early advantages can grow to become large successes, which is why glowing reviews, stellar ratings, and top listings are so important early on.

In writing this piece, I contacted my friend to reflect on his own email request.  Would he be brazen, bashful, remorseful?  He responded:

I see my email as a piece of shameless self-promotion with friends, like sending an article to colleagues, or telling someone you just published a book (and of course implying that buying it would be a good idea) … trying to get friends to buy the app is a common practice, but scarcely new to the online marketplace. Nor is getting your product in the best seller list new. Publishers of books and music have been trying to do it for decades.

Postscript: If you like this blog post, forward it to as many friends as possible!

Reblog this post [with Zemanta]
Phil Davis

Phil Davis

Phil Davis is a publishing consultant specializing in the statistical analysis of citation, readership, publication and survey data. He has a Ph.D. in science communication from Cornell University (2010), extensive experience as a science librarian (1995-2006) and was trained as a life scientist. https://phil-davis.com/

Discussion

5 Thoughts on "Gaming the Rating System"

It’s interesting that the engineering of the Web can help drive and reveal this simultaneously. But it’s nothing new. Authors have been trading book blurbs for decades now — I especially love the “early praise” comments on books, which I think are very often blurb barters. Attention isn’t easy to generate, the clutter is not easy to cut through. But there is a line between the legitimate and the suspect. Unfortunately, it’s like the batter’s box in baseball — each player scuffs it just enough so that by the middle innings, you can’t tell where the lines once were.

Promotion versus Manipulation

Good point, Kent. There is a fine line between promotion and manipulation. We believe that promotion (even self-promotion) is acceptable but manipulation implies some form of deception.

The use of pseudonyms implies a deceptive act, as does the payment (money or in-kind reviews) to the reviewer.

Exactly right. Promotion should be transparent. There’s a reason newspapers and magazines label those fake articles as “advertisements”, and it’s even more imperative for scholarly publishers whose business depends on their reputation.

It’s something that worries me about all the proposed substitutions for the impact factor for judging papers and journals. The impact factor is fatally flawed (the lack of transparency in the “secret formula” makes it impossible to judge), but it’s not easily gamed by running an autovoter or an autodownloader program, or setting up a shill account to give yourself good reviews. Yes, it can be (and is) gamed, but like most things on the internet, the ability to game scales way up for the proposed systems.

Comments are closed.